"The cost of liberty is less than the price of repression." - W. E. B. Du Bois, American writer
The recent significant fall in implicit volatilities in recent days, means that long date volatilities (1 year) of most significant equity indices are now testing the frontier level between the post-crisis regime and the ultra low regime of 2004-2007.
Implicit 1 year volatility for the S and P500 (SPX) - source Bloomberg:
Could
it be an attractive entry point or more simply a clear indication of regime
change? We have to agree with our-good cross-asset friend namely that we have a
hard time believing in the regime change when taking into account the
fundamental macro picture. Could it simply be the broader impact of financial
repression? One
has to wonder.
Financial liberalization, for instance in Emerging Markets, has been a good way to attract foreign investments. It has often led to a rise in volatility given investors had been reaping in the process higher daily return rates. When equity market becomes more open,
there are increases in stock return volatility (on the subject see the study realised by Vuong Thanh Long, Department of Economic Development and Policies at the Vietnam Development Forum - Tokyo Presentation - August 2007).
Regime switches also lead to potentially large consequences for investors' optimal portfolio choice hence the importance of the subject.
In relation to Regime Changes and Financial Markets, Andrew Ang, from Columbia University and NBER, and Allan Timmermann from the University of California, San Diego, made an interesting study in June 2011-
Regime Changes and Financial Markets:
"When
applied to financial series, regimes identified by econometric methods often
correspond to different periods in regulation, policy, and other secular
changes. For example, interest rate behavior markedly changed from 1979 through
1982, during which the Federal Reserve changed its operating procedure to
targeting monetary aggregates. Other regimes identified in interest rates
correspond to the tenure of different Federal Reserve Chairs (see, for example,
Sims and Zha, 2006). In
equities, different regimes correspond to periods of high and low volatility,
and long bull and bear market periods. Thus,
regime switching models can match narrative stories of changing fundamentals
that sometimes can only be interpreted ex post, but in a way that can be used
for ex-ante real-time forecasting, optimal portfolio choice, and other economic
applications.
Second,
regime switching models parsimouniously capture stylized behavior of many
financial series including fat tails, persistently occurring periods of
turbulence followed by periods of low volatility (ARCH effects), skewness, and
time-varying correlations. By appropriately mixing conditional normal (or other
types of) distributions, large amounts of non-linear effects can be generated.
Even when the true model is unknown, regime switching models can provide a good
approximation for more complicated processes driving security returns. Regime
switching models also nest as a special case jump models, since a jump is a
regime which is immediately exited next period and, when the number of regime
is large, the dynamics of a regime switching model approximates the behavior of
time-varying parameter models where the continuous state space of the parameter
is appropriately discretized.
Finally,
another attractive feature of regime switching models is that they are able to
capture nonlinear stylized dynamics of asset returns in a framework based on
linear specifications, or conditionally normal or log-normal distributions,
within a regime. This makes asset pricing under regime switching analytically
tractable. In particular, regimes introduced into linear asset pricing models
can often be solved in closed form because conditional on the underlying
regime, normality (or log-normality) is recovered. This makes incorporating
regime dynamics in affine models straight forward.
The
notion of regimes is closely linked to the familiar concept of good and bad
states or states with low versus high risk, but surprising and somewhat
counterintuitive results can be obtained from equilibrium asset pricing models
with regime changes. Conventional linear asset pricing models imply a positive
and monotonic risk-return relation (e.g., Merton, 1973). In contrast, changes
between discrete regimes with different consumption growth rates can lead to
increasing, decreasing, flat or non-monotonic risk/return relations as shown
by, e.g., Backus and Gregory (1993), Whitelaw (2000), and Ang and Liu (2007). Intuitively,
non-monotonic patterns arise because “good” and “bad” regimes, characterized by
high and low growth in fundamentals and asset price levels, respectively, may
also be associated with higher uncertainty about future prospects than more
stable, “normal” regimes which are likely to last longer. The possibility of
switching across regimes, even if it occurs relatively rarely, induces an
important additional source of uncertainty that investors want to hedge against. Inverse risk-return trade-offs can
result in some regimes because the market portfolio hedges against adverse
future consumption shocks even though the level of uncertainty (return
volatility) is high in these regimes. Further non-linearities can be generated
as a result of investors’ learning about unobserved regimes."
As highlighted above, the importance of regime change is paramount to asset allocation given:
*Hence the reason why retail investors have been net sellers of stocks since 2007.
"The seed of revolution is repression." - Woodrow Wilson
Stay tuned!
"-The relation between the investor horizon of a buy-and-hold strategy
and the optimal portfolio varies considerably from one regime to the
other.
-For example, in a bear regime, stocks are less favored and short-term
investors allocate a smaller part of their portfolio to stocks.*
-On the contrary, in the longer run, there is a high probability to switch to
a better regime and long-term investors dedicate a larger part of their
portfolio to stocks.
-In a bear regime the share allocated to stocks increases with the
investor’s horizon."
*Hence the reason why retail investors have been net sellers of stocks since 2007.
"Since they started selling in April 2007, eight months before the start of the Great Recession, individual investors have pulled at least $380 billion from U.S. stock funds, a category that includes both mutual funds and exchange-traded funds, according to estimates by the AP. That is the equivalent of all the money they put into the market in the previous five years.” (“AP IMPACT: Ordinary folks losing faith in stocks”, AP News)
"The seed of revolution is repression." - Woodrow Wilson
Stay tuned!
No comments:
Post a Comment